Posted by Unknown |

A Critique of the Contributions of George Joseph Stigler to the Development of Economic Thought.

Columnist: Daniel, Uzoigwe Chimezie


 
George Joseph Stigler: Nobel Prize Winner in Economic Science(1982).






                                        





   SECTION ONE
INTRODUCTION: GEORGE JOSEPH STIGLER
BIRTH
George Joseph Stigler was born in Seattle, Washington D.C on January 17, 1911. A US Economist, Joseph Stigler is one of history’s most outstanding modern economists.
EDUCATION
Stigler graduated from the University of Washington in 1931 with a B.A and then spent a year at Northwestern University from which he obtained his M.B.A in 1932. It was during his studies at the Northwestern University that Stigler developed an interest in economics and decided on an academic career. Due to a tuition scholarship that he received from the University of Chicago, Stigler enrolled at the university in 1933 to study Economics and went on to earn his Ph.D. in Economics from the University of Chicago in 1938. Stigler was one of four Students that ever managed to complete their Ph.D dissertation under Frank Knight in his 28 years at Chicago.
SPECIALIZATION
Stigler confined a large part of his study to microeconomics once stating, “I know very little macroeconomics, and I thank God for it everyday, because it changes once a year.” Within Microeconomics, his contributions were far-reaching. He also wrote extensively on the history of economic thought and also contributed to several aspects of the field of Industrial Organization.
INFLUENCE
George Joseph Stigler was greatly influenced by his Ph.D Supervisor, Frank Knight at the University of Chicago. Other Economists who influenced him include Jacob Viner, Henry Simons and Milton Friedman, his friend and colleague at the Chicago School.
In the same vein, He influenced Jacques Dreze, Thomas Sowell, Kenneth Lyon and many of his Students throughout his career. As part of his special interest in the study of history of economic thought, He did a lot of analysis on the works of Adam Smith but opposed Lord John Maynard Keynes. He is better associated with the Chicago school of thought and thisaccounts for the intellectual rapport between him and Milton Friedman, who was his friend and colleague at the Chicago school. 
CAREER AND SERVICE
Stigler’s teaching experience began in 1936 at Iowa state College where He taught until 1938. He spent much of the World War II period at Columbia University, performing mathematical and statistical research for the Manhattan project. He then spent one year at Brown University from where he proceeded to serve on the Columbia faculty from 1947 to 1958. He later lectured at the London School of Economics (LSE).
Stigler went on to become the Charles R. Walgreen Distinguished Service Professor of American Institutions, and Director of the Walgreen Foundation, Graduate School of Business, at the University of Chicago. In 1941, Stigler became a member of the Research Staff of the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER). He was also a member of the American Philosophical Society, the American Economic Association, the Royal Economic Society as a Fellow, and the American Statistical Association. He later became the President of the American Economic Association.
In 1971, Stigler became the Vice-Chairman of the Securities Investors protective Commission, and in 1969-70, He was a member of the Blue Ribbon Defense Panel. In 1960-61, He was Chairman of the Price Statistics Review Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research. In 1954-55, Stigler served as a member of the Attorney General’s Committee for the Study of Anti-Trust Laws.
He was a founding member of the Mont Pelerin Society, and was President of the Society from 1976 to 1978.
PUBLICATIONS
Stigler has a number of publications to his credit. He left behind a well-known intellectual legacy as embodied in his books, his over 100 major articles, and his many book reviews and short works. StigIer’s work, collectively, has been cited over 4,800 times from 1955 through 1983, according to Science Citation Index (SCI) and Social Sciences Citation Index (SSCI).However, Stigler’s most notable works and most-highly cited as reported in the “Web of Science” as at 19/7/2002include but not limited to:
The Theory of Economic regulation (1971)
The Economics of Information (1961)
De Gustibus Non EstDisputandum(1977)
A Theory of oligopoly (1964)
Information In the Labour Market (1962)
The Economics of scale (1958)
Perfect Competition, Historically Contemplated (1957)

However, what could be said to be Stigler’s magnum opus is his seminal studies of industrial structures, functioning of markets, and causes and effects of public regulation and the economics of information for which he was awarded the Nobel prize in 1982. However, as Coase (1982) would argue, Stigler’s studies of the history of economic thought is where he is seen at his best.

AWARDS/HONOURS
Stigler earned many honours and awards for his contributions in the field of Economics most notably the National Medal of Science (1987). When in 1982, Stigler was awarded the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences; many saw it as long overdue. Ronald Coase, another Nobel Laureate particularly described the award as something that was clearly right, in a world in which so much offends. When Stigler died in 1992, it was clear the field of Economic science had lost a Colossus and an intellectual powerhouse.
In the next section, we review Stigler’s most important contributions to economic thought.

                                         SECTION TWO
A REVIEW OF STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE DEVELOPMENT OF ECONOMIC THOUGHT
The contributions of George Joseph Stigler to the growth and development of economic thought are immense. In this section, we attempt to examine the key aspects of Stigler’s most important contributions to economic thought and the contributions cited by the Nobel Committee merit particular attention.
1.      THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION AND SEARCH

ORIGIN OF THE THEORY
The theory of perfect competition in product and resource markets implies a singleprice for goods or resources of homogeneous quality. Yet price and wage surveys and product and labour market studies reveal a variance in prices and wage rates even within narrowly defined product and occupational groupings. In the early 1960s Stigler wrote two important articles that helped explain this evidence.
                                    THE CRUX OF THE THEORY      
He observed that the one-price (one-wage) market will occur only where the cost of information about the prices (wages) offered by buyers and sellers is zero. In most situations, information is scarce and costly to obtain, and therefore it can be thought of as an economic good. Acquiring information entails costs and yields benefits, just as does obtaining all other economic goods. Because of this reality, market equilibrium will be characterized not by a single price but rather by a distribution of prices (wages) whose variance is related to the cost of searching for information. People and firms will judge it too costly to search for all of the information required to eliminate price (wage) variability. The greater the search costs, other things equal, the greater the dispersion of prices.
STIGLER’s FINDINGS (THE MODEL OF OPTIMAL ECONOMIC SEARCH)
Stigler was the first to develop a formal model of optimal economic search, which he applied to the product and resource markets. An explanation of search in the labour market will establish the general principle. Evidence indicates that those seeking employment recognize that wages paid for similar work vary among employers. Suppose that workers know the variance of the wage distribution andcan at least roughly estimate its mean, but they do not know which employer isoffering which wage. Therefore, they find it in their interest to search for the bestjob offer. Stigler asked, “Do they search until they have received every offer possible, therefore eliminating all but the highest one?”  If not, what determines the optimal length of their search? Figure 24B-1 below explains Stigler’s thinking on this subject.
The vertical axis measures the marginal benefit (MB) and marginal cost (MC) to a hypothetical person of successive days of job search. The horizontal axis shows the number of days devoted to searching (N).
Stigler stipulates that Search costs are of two types. The first are the direct costs, which include “for hire” notices, resume costs, postage, and transportation costs. These expenses tend to rise with additional search. Normally, the person begins the search closest to home, where the costs of obtaining job information are lower. As the search broadens, these costs tend to rise. The second cost is the opportunity cost of using one’s time to search for a better offer. Once an offer is in hand, the person could accept it and presumably immediately begin earning income. By continuing to search, these earnings are sacrificed. This opportunity cost is particularly large in those situations where the offer cannot be “stored”; that is, where the recipient of the offer must either accept it or reject it within a short period. In either case, a significant cost of continued job search is the earnings foregone by not taking the previous best opportunity. As the searcher receives and fails to accept higher wage offers, the marginal cost (MC) of additional days of search rises.
The marginal benefit curve (MB) in Figure A above slopes downward and to the right. A job search increases the likelihood of discovering better wage opportunities, but there are diminishing marginal benefits to the number of days devoted to job search. The present value of the increased income expected from an additional day of search falls as more information is gathered and more days go by.
As seen in the graph, the optimal length of job search for this individual is N1, at this point; the marginal benefit and cost of search are equal. Stigler said job search is but another human economic activity that lends itself to analysis by way of the marginal calculus. “Frictional” or “job search” unemployment results from imperfect information and the desire by those unemployed to spend an optimal amount of time searching for a job.
Because Stigler’s theory of information and search admits that wages and prices for similar commodities or services do not equalize under competitive pressures, it may appear to fall within the tradition of the imperfect competition theories of Robinson and Chamberlin. These theories challenged the competitive model and implied that greater government involvement was needed in the economy. But this interpretation is misleading, if not incorrect. Stigler’s theory indicates that the existence of price and wage variability for similar goods and resources is not only compatible with economic efficiency, where there are positive costs of acquiring information, but is necessary to achieve economic efficiency under these conditions.
His theory therefore attempts to show that unregulated markets normally produce society’s maximum well-being.
2.      STIGLER’S THEORY OF REGULATION (THE ‘CAPTURE THEORY’)
ORIGIN OF THE THEORY
According to Stigler, regulation can also be analysed as an economic good supplied and demanded because of potential gains to the parties involved. Those regulated gain through the direct subsidies, entry controls, price fixing, and so forth that regulation confers. This gain may exceed the costs of adhering to the rules and meeting the standards set by the regulators.
THE CRUX OF THE THEORY
Political leaders and regulators are usually willing to supply regulation because they benefit from the endorsements, campaign contributions, and votes that politically effective coalitions can provide. Winning elections provides continued employment, both for those elected and those appointed to government positions. Rather than promoting an efficient allocation of resources, regulation tends to serve the interests of those regulated at the expense of the broader public.
STIGLER’S FINDINGS
Groups who have intense and focused interest tend to “capture” the regulatory system and use it for their own self-interest. This is why Stigler’s theory on regulation is also termed the “capture” theory.  The big gains to the coalitions are paid for through losses to others. These losses individually are small but collectively exceed the gains to those regulated. Because the individual losses are small and the transaction costsof organizing large numbers of people are large, the losers may not have sufficientincentive to express their opposition.
Those firms, occupational groups, or other interest groups who have much to gain through control of the regulatory process will tend to prevail. The politician and the regulator thus are endogenous elements in Stigler’s system. Rather than being the outside referees maintaining rules that promote efficiency, elected officials and their appointees tend to be captured by those they regulate.
The policy implication of this theory is that, in many cases, less regulation, as opposed to more, is likely to improve economic well-being.
3.      STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION
ORIGIN
 In economics, the subject of industrial organization means, as the Swedish Academy indicates, ‘the study of market processes and the structure of industries.’ However, according to Coase (1982) for reasons which are not altogether clear, it is a field which has come to concentrate on The Monopoly Problem and, more specifically in the United States, on the problems thrown up by the administration of the antitrust laws. The result has not been a happy one for economics.
THE CRUX OF STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION
By concentrating on the problem of monopoly in dealing with an economic system which is, broadly speaking, competitive, economists had left unexplained many of the salient features of the economic systemor have been content with very defective explanations. The link with the administrationof the antitrust laws has tended to make matters worse by importing into economics an imprecise analysis which abounds in the judges’ opinions in antitrust cases.
STIGLER’S FINDINGS
Stigler’s articles on industrial organization are reprinted in The Organization of Industry (1968), and most are concerned with monopoly and antitrust policy. However, as Coase (1982), he transcends the weakness of most discussions of these questions by an impressive use of empirical data (as in “The Economic Effects of the Antitrust Laws”), by an analysis more precise and more searching (as in “Price and Non-price Competition”or “A Theory of Oligopoly”), and by discussing interesting and significant problems (as in “The Division of Labour Is Limited by the Extent of the Market”). Nonetheless, although the analysis proceeds at a much higher level than is usual, it remains true that most of the subjects discussed are those commonly dealt with under the heading of industrial organization.
But Stigler is not like the others. Like a mountain raised by a volcanic eruption, standing high and strange in the surrounding landscape, there is to be found in ‘The Organization of Industry’ a paper of a quite different kind.
4.      A THEORY OF OLIGOPOLY
ORIGIN OF THE THEORY
Economists had always agreed that Oligopolists wish to collude to maximize joint profits. In his theory, Stigler basically agree with the hypothesis but sought to reconcile this with facts, such as that collusion is impossible for many firms and collusion is much more effective in some circumstances than others. Stigler espoused these views in his ‘A Theory of Oligopoly’ (1964).
THE CRUX OF STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS
Stigler argues that a satisfactory theory of oligopoly cannot begin with assumptions concerning the way in which each firm views its interdependence with its rivals. The traditional theory of profit-maximizing enterprises has the notion that behaviour is not something to be assumed but something to be deduced. With this in mind, it can be said that firms in an industry will behave in such a way, given the demand and supply functions (including those of rivals), that their profits will be maximized.
Stigler stipulates that the combined profits of the entire set of firms in an industry are maximized when they act together as a monopolist. In the traditional formulation of the oligopoly problem, in which there are no major uncertainties as to the profit-maximizing output and price at any time with this result holding for any number of firms.
SUMMARY OF STIGLER’S FINDINGS
Stigler modified the traditional formulation of the oligopoly problem. He presented a systematic account of the factors governing the feasibility of collusion, which like most things in this world is not free. Stigler looked critically at the concept of homogeneity of products, and what it implies for profit-maximizing. He showed that collusion normally involves much more than “the” price.
Homogeneity is commonly defined in terms of identity of products or of (what is presumed to be equivalent) pairs of products between which the elasticity of substitution is infinite. Stigler opines that it is the behaviour of buyers that is decisive. Yet, it should be that products may be identical to any or every buyer while buyers may be quite different from the view point of sellers.
Stigler was of the view that once collusion has been effected, and a price structure established, any member of the agreement can secretly violate it and gain larger profits than by conforming to it. He identified fixing market shares as the most efficient of all methods of combating secret price reductions because no one can profit from price-cutting if he is moving along the industry demand curve once a maximum profit price has been chosen.
5.      STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE FIELD OF PUBLIC POLICY
ORIGIN OF THE THEORY
The field of public policy involves the study of specific policy problems and governmental responses to them. It is a field that is on the borderline between politics and Economics. Thus, it was treated under the field of political economy before economics and politics became separate disciplines (Dryzek, 2008). The study of public policy attempts to devise solutions for problems of public concern. Such issues studied under public policy include healthcare, pollution and the economy. Generally, public policy represents government’s plans and strategies for the development of particular sectors of the economy or the whole economy itself. Thus, we can have public policy on transport, communication, education and health. On the other hand, a national policy for growth and development would be seen as a public policy for the whole economy.
THE CRUX OF THE THEORY
In a paper, ‘Economists and Public Policy’ published in 1982, Stigler argued in a thesis that Economists have a deplorable habit of giving emphatic advice  on public policy without bothering- even if they live long after- to see whether their productions of the effects of the policy were correct.
He substantiated this by saying that in the mid-nineteenth century, Nassau Senior and Robert Torrens predicted dire consequences for the textile industry if the British Parliament passed the ten-hour day bill. He however stated that each of the famous Economists lived for seventeen years after the bill was passed, but neither of them found the time to examine its actual effects.
He also partially recanted an earlier thesis in which He asserted that once the practice of testing predictions by examining the evidence became general practice, economist’s advice – that is, the advice that survived the empirical tests- would be heeded by the Society. For truth, even temporary truth, is a God that that the rational society must worship.


SUMMARY OF STIGLER’S FINDINGS
Stigler argued in his theses that a society will not challenge for long established truths about the real World, because that is unwise behaviour no matter what one is seeking to do. To disregard the real World is to act inefficiently. For example, Stigler argues that Economists confirm Walter J. Wessel’s proposition that a legislated minimum wage is largely vitiated by the ability of employers to reduce fringe benefits and costly working conditions (Economic Inquiry, April 1980). Then, the labour unions which support such laws would surely address this means of frustrating their desired increase in the cost of employing workers who receive low wage rates. Stigler continued by incorporating hard science in his analysis.
                                    The Place of Hard Science
Stigler noted that there are things that economists know withgreat confidence about the working of an economic system. The price of a commodity will rise when its supply falls, even if the state passes a law against a price rise: the rise willthen simply take the form of legal or illegalcosts in getting the rationed commodity-waitingin line or buying in a black market. A largeand rapid rise in the supply of money will lead to a rise in prices (again, possibly concealed but not avoided by public controls). A competitive industry will refuse in the long run to supply its product at less than a cost-remunerative price, and will be unable to get much more.
Stigler opined that such elementary and even platitudinous findings are deducible from first principles and illustrated by many thousands of documentable instances. Stigler argues that these were the sorts of findings which that were inescapable and therefore irresistible to an intelligent society.
Stigler believes that if we look at any important economic policy of the state, we shall find that it takes account of whatever established knowledge economists possess, and perhaps of some that we do not yet possess. The theory of price discrimination, for example, emphasizes the possibility of profiting from differences among buyers in the “intensity” of their demand for a product when they can be prevented from reselling to one another. He said that this theory is fully recognized in the regulation of the structure of public utility prices.

Public Policy-making: The Presence of Other Values
Here, Stigler argues that there were other important (both economic and non-economic values) that influence public policies. He started by recognizing the errors Economists (including himself) normally make in their analysis. For example, Economists expect the society eventually to believe their case for free trade and the case against minimum wages and the case for free energy prices (subsidy removal or deregulation of the downstream sub-sector) and our case against rent controls. Every one of these recommendations is based on a tolerably accurate analysis of the effects of the policies on aggregate social income. Yet the Society often pursues very different economic policies. Stigler explains this divergence by saying that the Society usually factors in other values which Economists do not usually consider critical in their analysis. Such values the society consider in the actual implementation of public policies include the need for redistribution of income, reducing wide income inequality gap and improving the standard of living for the general citizenry.
Reflections on the Chicago Credo
The Chicago represents the general idea of what guides the working of the markets as enunciated by the Chicago School of Thought which Stigler is part of. The credo states that people act efficiently in their own interests. Using this credo, Stigler argues that people who make automobiles on average know better what to make and how to make it than the best industrial economists. The worker who chooses an education and a craft on average knows better how to choose than the best labour economist. The householder who buys a consumer good on average knows better what and where to buy than the best home economist.
This is not to say that the economic world is perfect-although it really is pretty impressive- or that its imperfections can never be discovered by an economist-although it is hard to find an example. The credo also asserts that economic agents learn all the presently knowable things it pays them to know-always on average-and act with due regard for this knowledge. The credo asserts that nothing is easier than for an economist to be wiser in 1982 than the American automobile industry was in 1972, but no economist in 1982 is so wise as the automobile industry in 1982 or even in 1981 (Stigler, 1982).
 Stigler linked the invention of the credo tothe cornerstone of Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations (1776).  Smith’s observation was that “the statesman, who should attempt to direct private people in what manner they ought to employ their capitals, would not only load himself with a most unnecessary attention, but assume an authority which could safely be trusted, not only to no single person, but to no council or senate whatever, and which would nowhere be so dangerous as in the hands of a man who had folly and presumption enough to fancy himself fit to exercise it.
Stigler extended the Chicago credo to the larger society where the society is expected to act efficiently in public decision-making depending on the values that are critical to such society despite divergent advice offered by Economists.
6.      STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO PRICE THEORY
ORIGIN OF THE THEORY
Standard Economics is usually divided into two major fields. The first part is the price theory (otherwise known as Microeconomics) and the second is macroeconomics. The price theory explains how the interplay of supply and demand in competitive markets creates a multitude of individual prices, wage rates, profit margins, and rental charges. The price theory assumes that people behave rationally. Consumers try to spend their income in ways that give them as much pleasure as possible (maximize their utility). On the other hand, entrepreneurs seek as much profit as they can extract from their operations (maximize profitability).
Price theory has been part of economic discourse even before Adam Smith published his Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of nations (1776). However, these discussions were indirect and were not distinguishable from moral philosophy and politics. It is to be noted that before Adam Smith’s magnum opus, past economic  philosophers including Plato, Aristotle have treated price theories under different names like value and exchange and monetary theory.
However, it was Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations that unravelled the principles of economics and enunciated on the price theory. Smith captured this under the several classical economic laws including the self-interest law, the law of value, the law of wages, the law of rent, profit and interest and the law of markets (Okoh, 2006). It was later that the acclaimed father of Neo-classical economics, Alfred Marshall developed further on the price theory particularly in his masterly neo-classicist work “Principles of Economics” (1890). In this work, Marshall explained demand by the principle of marginal utility, and supply by the rule of marginal productivity (the cost of producing the last item of a given quantity). In competitive markets, consumer preferences for low prices of goods and seller preferences for high prices were adjusted to some mutually agreeable level. At any actual price, then, buyers were willing to purchase precisely the quantity of goods that sellers were prepared to offer (Lekachman, 2008).
As in markets for consumer goods, this same reconciliation between supply and demand occurred in markets for money and human labour. In money markets, the interest rate matched borrowers with lenders. The borrowers expected to use their loans to earn profits larger than the interest they had to pay. Savers, for their part, demanded a price for postponing the enjoyment of their own money. A similar accommodation had to be made in wages paid for human labour. In competitive labour markets, wages actually paid represented at least the value to the employer of the output attributed to hours worked and at least acceptable compensation to the employee for the tedium and fatigue of the work.
Later, many modern economists made their own contributions to price theory which was now distinct. Stigler was just one of these economists. In what follows, we attempt to summarize Stigler’s contributions to price theory, a subject which interested Stigler throughout his career.
SUMMARY OF STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO PRICE THEORY
Stigler defined price theory as the study of the factors affecting the value set by sellers on their goods. Stigler began his empirical work in price theory in the mid- 1940s, soon after moving to Columbia University, New York. Indeed, he published what was perhaps the first example of linear programming in a paper entitled “The cost of subsistence.”(1945). His work also included the statistical investigation of a specialized theory of rigid price structures (in “the Kinky Oligopoly Demand Curve and Rigid Prices” published in 1947), and a paper on the factors governing the delivered prices of commodities (“A theory of delivered price systems” published in 1949). In 1946, he published a landmark book, “The Theory of Price.” After two revisions, in 1952 and again in 1966, it is still used in graduate schools throughout the US (Essays of an Information Scientist). It has been cited over 260 times through 1983.Stigler also co-authored another importantempirical study of prices in 1970,
“The Behaviour of Industrial Price” published in 1966 (75 citations through 1983). The book examines the question of price stability and presents meticulous data collected by Stigler and his colleague James K. Kindahl, University of Massachusetts, Amherst.
The book’s statistical evidence helped undermine the long-standing economic maxim that a major segment of the economy sets prices by management decision rather than in reaction to market factors.
7   STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO IMPERFECTIONS IN THE CAPITAL MARKET.
ORIGIN OF THE THEORY
Although, the classical orthodoxy had long established that the invisible hand works to establish a perfect working system, what we obtain in real life is usually different. Markets are usually imperfect in practical life and this is what Stigler explored in his contributions to capital market imperfections.

SUMMARY OF STIGLER’S FINDINGS
Stigler’s contributions to the theory of imperfect capital markets are contained in his work, Imperfections in the Capital Market(1967). In this work, Stigler described the imperfections in the capital market as not only a popular but a “terminal” one. By “terminal”, Stigler, was inferring that it was a very important issue but had received little or no attention as at that time. In making his contributions, Stigler identified two key imperfections in the capital market:
Inability to borrow cheaply:Stigler identified this as the basic imperfection in the capital market due to the inefficiencies in the capital market. Inefficiency in the capital market leads to a mis-allocation of capital especially when the costs of transactions are high. When borrowers of funds cannot get cheap funds, it signals inefficiency in the capital market.
Monopoly as an Imperfection: According to Stigler (1957), there is ample historical precedent for identifying a perfect market with a competitive market. Stigler argues that monopoly power could lead to serious inefficiency in the allocation of capital.He however did not see this inefficiency caused by monopoly power to be too large since capital is the most fungible, the most divisible, and the most mobile of all productive resources.
Stigler concludes by saying that the efficiency of markets should be of great interest to the economist. Although, Stigler admits that it was not possible to have perfect markets, he enjoined economists to continue to work towards developing theories on how to reduce the inefficiency of real markets and make them work better.


SECTION THREE
EVALUATION
A GENERAL EVALUATION OF STIGLER’S WORKS
George Joseph Stigler’s contributions to the development of economic thought are varied. This is because Stigler contributed a lot to different fields of economics including but not limited to the Price theory, industrial organization, public policy, the history of economic thought, the functioning of markets, the Economics of Information and Search and Public regulation.
An examination of his works shows that Stigler is an Economist who is very analytical and always detailed in his approach. More to this is the fact that Stigler always likes to subject his theories to empiricism. He always endeavours to reconcile the theoretical World and the real World by subjecting his theoretical postulations to real World data tests to ensure that they are valid. This is reflected in most of his works which are always accompanied with quantitative analysis.
This was acknowledged by Ronald Coase (in an appreciation) where he wrote that ‘what remarkable is the variety of ways in which Stigler handles a problem; he moves from the marshalling of high theory to aphorism to detailed statistical analysis, a mingling of treatments which resemble, in this respect, the “subtle and colourful”Edgeworth (Francis Edgeworth who developed the box diagram still being applied to international trade theory today is noted for his graceful and analytical approach to economic analysis). It is by a magic of his own that Stigler arrives at conclusions which are both unexpected and important.’
But this is not to say that there are no reservations with Stigler’s works. An examination of Stigler’s works show a high level of abstraction in his analysis and Stigler’s analytical language usually sound very esoteric. According to 1970 Nobel prize-winning economist, Paul Samuelson, (Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Cambridge), not all of Stigler’s conclusions are universally accepted. In the utility rate study, for example, the evidence could also be interpreted to support the view that the unregulated industries kept their rates competitive out of fear of regulation.
However, according to Coase,even those who have reservations about his conclusions will find that a study of his argument has enlarged their understanding of the problem being discussed and that aspects are revealed which were previously hidden. Coase continues by saying that Stigler ‘never deals with a subject which he does not illuminate. And he expresses his views in a style uniquely Stiglerian, penetrating, lively, and spiced with wit. His writings are easy to admire, a joy to read, and impossible to imitate. He is a man sui generis. Age shall not wither nor custom stale George Stigler’s infinite variety.’
It could also be said that some of Stigler’s contributions remain valid today although latter-day economists may have improved upon them. Stigler’s iconic contributions still form part of the embodiment of microeconomics and these contributions continue to be relevant to today’s society.
In the part that follows, we attempt an evaluation of Stigler’s theoretical contributions already discussed above with the aim of identifying the strengths and weaknesses (where applicable) of the theories and assessing their practical relevance to society and today’s economic world.
1.      THE ECONOMICS OF INFORMATION AND SEARCH
STRENGTHS OF THE THEORY
a.       Stigler was the first to develop a formal theory of optimal economic search.
b.      Stigler did not only develop a model of optimal economic search, he applied it to the product and resource markets.
c.       Stigler’s contributions to the Economics of Information and Search were ground-breaking and were backed with lots of statistical and mathematical proofs using the geometric tools of economics.
d.      Stigler provided the platform for further theorizing on the Economics of Information and Search.

WEAKNESSES OF THE THEORY
The theory could be said to be highly abstracted the way Stigler developed it and the practical utility of the model of optimal economic search continues to be questioned.
RELEVANCE OF THE THEORY TO TODAY’S SOCIETY
Stigler’s Economics of Information was built upon by George Akerlof, Michael Spence and Joseph Stiglitz all of who co-won the 2001 Nobel prize in Economic Sciences in 2001. Today, Information Economics focuses on the study of how inadequate or imperfect information can influence a market. The Economics of Information stipulates that markets operate inefficiently if buyers and sellers act with imperfect or inadequate information. If there is asymmetric information (if a seller has better information about product quality than a buyer), then a market is likely to collapse entirely or result in an offering of low-quality products that may cause the market to contract rather than grow.
On the other hand, despite criticisms, Stigler’s optimal model of Economic search has stood the test of time especially in product and resource markets. In product markets, it remains valid that in searching for a product, a consumer would not want to search further when the marginal cost exceeds the expected marginal benefit of the product itself. This also applies to resource markets when firms want to acquire both labour and capital resources for production purposes.
Therefore, Stigler’s contributions to the field of Economics of Information and Search remain valid till date.
2.      STIGLER’S THEORY OF REGULATION ( THE ‘CAPTURE’ THEORY)
STRENGTHS
a.       The theory was a ground-breaking theory as far as the economics of regulation is concerned.
b.      The theory accurately explains what happens behind the scene in the regulatory system when Politicians and their cohorts backed by political power ‘capture’ the regulatory system and take advantage of it.
c.       The ‘capture’ theory is a good explanation of the experience (of regulation) of developing countries (with weak institutions) which the elite in such societies usually subvert to favour themselves.
d.      Stigler established that less regulation was more favourable to the growth of markets and this has continued to be the view of modern economists.
e.       Stigler provided the basis for further intellectual cogitation in the theory of regulation by economic scholars.
WEAKNESS OF THE THEORY
a.       In modern times, Stigler’s theory of ‘capture’ is only applicable to developing Countries with weak institutions. The ‘capture’ theory cannot apply to developed countries with strong institutions that can checkmate the activities of Politicians and their cohorts in attempting to subvert the regulatory system.
b.      Although, Stigler’s argument that less regulation was more plausible than regulation, He did not explain what should apply (how markets can grow or whether growth was not feasible) when as a matter of necessity, the government regulates certain sectors for strategic reasons.
RELEVANCE OF STIGLER’S THEORY OF REGULATION TO TODAY’S SOCIETY.
In the modern society, Stigler’s ‘capture’ theory still remains a valid explanation of what happens behind-the-scene in the regulatory system (especially in developing countries) where the elite in such societies usually sabotage the regulatory system. This phenomenon still prevails till date.
Stigler argued that less regulation is friendlier to the growth of markets than regulation. Stigler’s idea has been the core working principle of global development institutions including the World Bank and the IMF who advocate deregulation in line with the tenets of the Washington Consensus (see Williamson, 1989). The World’s emerging economies have also embraced the tenet of deregulation as a more suitable approach to growing their economies. In line with this, Nigeria adopted the Structural Adjustment Programme (SAP) in 1986, a policy that sought to liberalize the Nigerian economy and diversify her economic base.
3        & 4 STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE FIELD OF INDUSTRIAL ORGANIZATION AND OLIGOPOLY.
We evaluate Stigler’s contributions to the field of industrial organization and oligopoly together since according to Ekanem (2012), current research in industrial economics, theoretical and empirical is focused on formal models of oligopoly.
STRENGTHS OF THE THEORY
a.       Stigler’s contributions to industrial organization was a timely intervention in the growing monopoly problem and the issue of anti-trust policy in the US in his time.
b.      Stigler in his The Organization of Industry (1968) was able to reconcile industrial economics with conventional price theory.
c.       Stigler was able to modify the traditional oligopoly theory making more explicit the motivation behind colluding firms and how collusion can lead to the maximization of profits by the firms involved.
d.      He added to existing knowledge on Industrial Organization and the Oligopoly problem and charted a course for further theorizing in the two fields.
WEAKNESSES OF THE THEORIES
a.       Many Economists disagree with Stigler that the subject of Industrial Economics is not a distinct sub-field of Economics, but coincides with conventional price theory (see Phillips and Steventon 1974). The current approach is to recognize industrial economics as a distinct branch of price theory.
b.      Stigler’s oligopoly theory did not explain how the excesses in collusion could be managed.
RELEVANCE TO TODAY’S SOCIETY
Today, industrial production constitutes one of the major drivers of global economic growth. Therefore, a study in industrial organization is an effort that is worthwhile. Stigler’s voice in the field of industrial organization added to the growing number of voices in the field which has made it to be studied as a distinct field of Economics as industrial economics.
The study of the oligopolistic market structures has remained the major concern of industrial economics. Stigler’s contributions in this regard have provided illumination into the workings of markets that are characterized by imperfect competition. These markets which cannot be analysed using the standard textbook competitive model according to (Schmalensee, 1987) are the forms of market that exist in real societies.
5        & 6. STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO THE FIELD OF PUBLIC POLICY AND THE PRICE THEORY
STRENGTHS OF THE THEORY
a.       Stigler advocated that economists should be meticulous enough to follow up on their advice to government on public policy issues in order to assess the performance of their advice as far as public policy-making and implementation is concerned.
b.      Stigler was able to recognize the presence of other values other than economic values in public policy-making. This is a more realistic approach to public policy issues.
c.       Stigler’s empirical approach to the study of price theory was novel and made more economic sense.
d.      Stigler’s studies into the price theory helped undermine the long-standing maxim that a major segment of the economy sets prices by management decision rather than in reaction to market forces.
e.       He cultivated the ground for further theorizing in these two fields.
WEAKNESSES OF THE THEORIES
a.       Stigler did not provide an ‘exhaustible’ list of other values (other than economic) that could influence public policy-making.
b.      The fact that Stigler identified strongly with the Chicago credo presents his views on public policy as one-sided since he did not recognize other divergent but veracious views as far as the issue of public policy is concerned.
c.       In developing countries (and some developed countries alike) where subsidies, minimum wages, price floors and ceilings are rampart, a major segment of the economy still sets prices by management decision rather than by the reaction of market forces as Stigler stipulated.


RELEVANCE OF THE THEORIES TO TODAY’S SOCIETY
In public policy-making, Stigler’s emphasis on the presence of other values other than economic values is worthy of note. This can be related to the public policy efforts of African countries Nigeria inclusive where public policies are made based only on economic considerations ignoring other values (socio-cultural and socio-political) of the African Society. The failure of the Structural Adjustment Programme in Nigeria and many other African countries could be attributed to this. The SAP pill (which was prepared based mainly on economic considerations) was just forced down the throat of most African Countries without consideration for the dynamic and peculiar socio-cultural and socio-political forces prevalent in African countries. This is contrasted with the experience of the East Asian Countries who rejected the SAP package, looked inwards (by reconciling developments efforts with the socio-cultural milieu) and experienced rapid growth in such a dimension that economists have aptly tagged their experience the ‘East Asian Miracle.’
In the same vein, Stigler’s empirical approach to the price theory has improved our understanding of microeconomics and increased its applicability in solving the problems of economic units – households, firms and governments.
7.      STIGLER’S CONTRIBUTIONS TO INEFFICIENCIES IN CAPITAL MARKETS
STRENGTH OF THE THEORY
-          Stigler was able to identify the inability to borrow cheaply as a basic imperfection in the capital market. This has continued to be the case to date.
WEAKNESS OF THE THEORY
-          Stigler did not recognize monopoly as a huge imperfection. However, in real life, no matter how fungible, divisible and mobile capital maybe, a firm with monopoly power can appropriate huge capital outlays toitself, kill competitors and entrench a huge imperfection in the capital market.
RELEVANCE TO TODAY’S SOCIETY
The issue of cost of borrowing has remained a topical issue in modern capital markets. Like Stigler stipulated, high operational costs has remained the bane of underdeveloped capital markets especially in developing countries.



CONCLUSION
In this work, we have attempted to review the contributions of George Joseph Stigler to the development of economic thought. In doing this, we find that though Stigler was interested in Microeconomics, He is a man of many parts given his varied contributions to the field in the area ofPrice theory, industrial organization, public policy, the history of economic thought, the functioning of markets, the Economics of Information and Search and Public regulation.
In his contributions, we find an Economist who is very exhaustive and analytical in his approach and promotes empiricism in his theorizing. An evaluation of these contributions reveals that despite societal dynamics, they still remain valid in modern economics and relevant to today’s society.
Stigler left an envious intellectual legacy in Economics in his time; it is now left for today’s Economists (including Students of Economics) to work towards making their own contributions to the development of economic thought in their own time.

REFERENCES
Coase, Ronald (1982): “George J. Stigler: An Appreciation.”
Dryzek, John. “Political Science.” Microsoft Encarta 2009 (DVD). Redmond, WA: Microsoft Corporation, 2008.
Friedland, Claire (1994). “Catalogue of the George Joseph Stigler Manuscripts in Special Collections, Regenstein Library, University of Chicago. Centre for the study of the Economy and the State. University of Chicago.
Okoh, S.E.N (2006). Selected Readings in the History of Economic thought.’ Mindex publishing, Benin-city.
Stigler, G. J. "Monopoly and Oligopoly by Merger," A.E.R., Vol. XL (May, 1950). .
- "Economics of Information," J.P.E. (June, 1961). .
- "Perfect Competition, Historically Contemplated," ibid. (February, 1957).Reprinted in Essays in the History of Eco-nomics. Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press, 1965. .
-The Theory of Price. 3d ed. New York: Macmillan Co., 1966
-   The Theory of Economic regulation (1971). University of Chicago Press.
 -     A Theory of oligopoly (1964). University of Chicago Press
-       Information In the Labour Market (1962). University of Chicago Press
-      Economists and Public Policy (1982). University of Chicago Press